Top Posters
Since Sunday
g
3
3
2
J
2
p
2
m
2
h
2
s
2
r
2
d
2
l
2
a
2
A free membership is required to access uploaded content. Login or Register.

Intentional Torts and Defense.docx

Uploaded: 6 years ago
Contributor: medulla
Category: Legal Studies
Type: Other
Rating: N/A
Helpful
Unhelpful
Filename:   Intentional Torts and Defense.docx (61.18 kB)
Page Count: 20
Credit Cost: 1
Views: 101
Last Download: N/A
Transcript
Intentional Torts & Defenses Consider extent of liability (causation), appropriateness of punitive damages, lack of insurance (by law) for intentional torts. Battery Vosburg (kick) Garrat (chair) White (piano) Where D’s act is (1) unlawful, (2) intentional, (3) with substantial certainty of contact; D is SL for damages that directly result. An act is unlawful when harm is intended or there is no license, explicit or implicit (e.g. playground). R.2d §13 Battery (a) intends harmful or offensive contact (b) harmful contact directly or indirectly results Mohr (ear surgery) Surgery is unlawful without informed consent. Complete immunity of person except w/r/t pleasantries and emergencies. Kennedy (surgery contrast) Consent may generally permit a remedy in an area of the original incision; family members or general forms may provide consent. Workers Compensation Acts Protects employers from neg. claims, but excludes intentional harms. Trespass & Conversion Dougherty (land survey) An unauthorised intrusion into the land of another is a trespass for which there are SL damages; if nothing more than treading down grass. Subject to emergency and defense of property exceptions. Intel Corp. (email) Trespass to chattels requires actual harm to the property. Conversion SL property tort; liability follows the economic benefits of the property. E.g. A B C Moore (DNA) Ps may not sue on a theory of conversion for cells removed from the body. Public policy favoring medical research prevents extension of the property right. Defenses Courvoisier (policeman) Ds not liable for self-defense that is (1) necessary, (2) reasonable, and (3) proportionate to the circumstances. R.2d/Bird Traps (e.g. spring guns) justified when D, if present, wd have been justified in the defense. Kirby ($50) Owners may use (1) necessary (2) reasonable and (3) proportionate force to retake property—only in hot pursuit. Except if property was willfully given. Ploof (dock) Trespass may be justified by necessity, whereupon landowner has no right to counter-trespass. Vincent (ropes) Where D intentionally acts on a necessity-based privilege, D is SL for compensatory damages. Negligence Strict Liability vs. Negligence Introduction & History Brown v. Kendall (dogfight) Where D’s intentional action is (1) lawful (consider social benefit) and (2) contact is unintentional, then the question is whether D exercised due care. No intentional tort, no SL. Rylands (resevoir) NUISANCE - D is SL for damages that result from the escape of a thing (1) unnatural; (2) likely to cause mischief; (3) newfangled technology. Except if contrib neg, act of God, 3rd party action. Collins (horse) Losee (boiler) Reject Rylands generally b/c of American ideas re: industry, progress; or specific’y whr P benefits from enterprise, activity. Powell (RR sparks) When no neg on part of D, SL rule imposes the cost to society upon the owner of a newfangled product. Holmes, The Common Law A duty to act reasonably w/r/t foreseeable harms provides man w/ the best guide to action… Stone (cricket) No negligence duty to prevent against unforeseeable (i.e. unprecedented) harms. Hammontree (seizure) D has a duty to exercise reasonable care of a person with the same condition. (no liability in this case) Basic Standard of Care Reasonable Person Roberts (old driver) D’s with disabilities have a duty to regulate their own actions. Daniels (minor) Minors engaged in an adult activity (e.g. driving) are held to the same standard of care as adults. Breunig (flying car!) Insane held to the same standard of care, EXCEPT when (1) institutionalized; (2) sudden mental incapacity Fletcher (blind P) D, city must tailor its conduct to the reality that the public contains ppl w/ a diversity of physical abilities. Calculus of Risk Eckert (RR baby) Heroic action to save human life cannot be negligent unless rash or reckless. Dst’g: hero consents to risk. Terry & Seavey Reasonableness in hero scenario may depend upon (1) Risk % (2) Value of P’s life (3) Value of child’s life (4) Utility/probability of success (5) % chance child survives w/o action (i.e. necessity %) Hand Formula Carroll Towing Osborne (car door) Cooley (wires) Risk Calculus: If C < P x L, then precaution is worthwhile Cost of precaution < Probability harm x magnitude of Loss *C includes the comparative risk of the adopted precautions; burden is on P to show practicability Negligence Policy Neg regime’s liability cliff may cause potential D’s to be too careful; SL yields optimal caution level Neg regime does not spur reduction in activity levels as well as SL regime Lyons (swerve) “Sudden emergency” unnecessary; confuses juries calculating what’s reasonable under the circumstances United Airlines Common carriers have a duty of utmost care. Custom Titus (narrow RR) D’s adherence to custom is dispositive. Shield. Mayhew (mine) Custom is not a defense when not consistent w/ ordinary prudence. TJ Hooper (radios) Despite no universal practice, not adoptin a practice is negligent when costs outweigh the benefits. Lama (bedrest) In the context of medical malpractice: Custom is dispositive Cost of disclosure weighed against the probability and severity of harm; requires P to demonstrate disclosure would cause a reasonable person to chose a different treatment. MedMal Policy Studdert, Brennan & Mello Problems: (1) Neg regime encourages defensive medicine, which drives up costs; (2) tort litigation tends to decrease the information flow after an adverse event; Reforms: (1) damage caps make cases unattractive for P’s attorneys; (2) Expert panels (a la Workers Comp) in lieu of juries; Obstacles: (1) P’s attorney bar; (2) skepticism of experts; (3) expressive function of tort; (4) use of expert panel may decrease communication b/w doctors and patients. Canterbury (back surgery) Doctor has a duty to disclose risks UNLESS (1) patient is unconscious and harm from a failure to treat is greater than harm of treatment; (2) disclosure poses a threat to the patient’s well being. The Role of Statutes & Regulation Osborne (poison) Violation of a statute may constitute negligence per se. (Consider: cts more likely to find liability in TORT) Gorris (sheep) For negligence per se, statute must be designed to prevent against the type of harm that occurred. (Consider: less likely to find liability in CONTRACT; BUT statute may be evidence of custom and feasibility) Martin (headlights) Violation of a statute w/o explanation may be negligence per se as a matter of law. (Consider: D acting against others’ safety) Tedla (roadwalkers) Violation of a statute may be only prima facie evidence of neg. (Consider P’s acting against own safety) Uhr v. East Greenbush Cent. Sch. Dist. Violation of a statute may imply negligence per se only if the statute implies a private right of action. Factors: (1) member of class leg enacted to protect; (2) private action promotes leg purpose; (3) private right consistent with the legislative scheme. Dram Shop Statutes OLD: shops not liable; drunk’s decision cut causal chain. NOW: some Jxs find liability based on (1) greater foreseeability of harm; (2) new attitudes re: alcoholism; (3) new norms re: drunk driving. Hand Formula. Judge vs. Jury Metropol. RR (UK) Judge decides whether neg may reasonably be inferred; jury decides if neg should be inferred. Baltimore&Ohio Ry (stop/look/listen) (Holmes) Rule: when the standard is clear it should be laid down once and for all by the ct. Pokora (S/L/L) (Cardozo) Standard: Judges may take the question from a jury only when one result obtains Proof of Negligence P’s evidence of Negligence Insufficient as a matter of law Sufficient: permissible inference of neg. Rebuttable presumption of neg. Dispositive: Neg as a matter of law D wins / no jury Q D or P / jury Q P (unless D shows evidence to create jury Q) P wins / no jury Q Byrne (flour barrel) Res ipsa IF: (1) accident not normal w/o neg, (2) D has exclusive control over instrumentality, (3) P rules out other the 3 other possible causes: (a) P’s voluntary conduct, (b) 3rd party conduct, (c) Act of god. THEN: burden shifts to D to show non-negligence. Colmenares (escalator) For Res Ipsa: look to whether D had a delegable duty to control the instrumentality. Ybarra (surgery) MedMal: where unusual injury occurs while P under anesthesia, liability falls on all Ds who had control over P’s body or instrumentalities that may cause the injury. Information forcing–D’s may cross-claim. Defenses Based on Plaintiff’s Conduct Butterfield Under CL contributory negligence is a complete defense. Beems (brakesman) No contributory negligence for P, brakeman, killed b/c foot was stuck. Gyerman (stacks) D has burden of proving all the elements of a contributory negligence defense, including causation. LeRoy Fibre Co. (stacks near tracks) One’s rights to own property cannot be limited by the wrongs of another (in claims for contributory neg). Coase entitlement shd disfavor cheapest cost avoider. Derheim (seatbelt) Seatbelt defense: depending on Jx, may reduce (comparative) or bar (contributory) the claim. May have no effect, given that non-use did not cause the accident. Fuller (RR&buggy) The party that had the last clear chance to avoid the accident bears the responsibility. (No longer necessary under comparative negligence regime). American Axe Where P voluntarily engages in an activity that has known or obvious danger, primary assumption of the risk is a complete bar. (Consider worker may quit or demand higher wages) Workers assume the risk of their fellow servants negligence. (Consider freedom of contract) Workplace Injury Before Workers Comp Employees faced 5 hurdles in claims against employers: must prove (1) negligence; and that (2) custom; (3) assumption of the risk; (4) contributory negligence; and (5) fellow servant rule – are not defenses. Steeplechase (slide) Where danger is an element of the appeal, primary assumption of the risk is a complete bar, EXCEPT IF: (1) risk is either too likely; (2) too severe; (3) latent risk. Primary vs. Secondary Assumption of the Risk Primary: D either does not have an ordinary duty of care (e.g. football) or there was no breach. Secondary: D has a duty, but P undertook the activity w/ knowledge of D’s negligence. Meistrich (ice rink) Where P acts w/ knowledge of D’s negligence, secondary assumption of the risk is a complete bar. (Can be characterized as P’s negligence under a comparative negligence regime). S-K-I Ltd. Waiver may be invalid for public policy if: (1) business is publicly regulated; (2) business is one of practical public necessity; (3) business holds itself out as available to any member of public; (4) business has decisive bargaining strength; (5) in using superior bargaining strength, business presents adhesion contract with no opt out; (6) P is placed under control of seller and subject to risk of carelessness. Comparative Negligence Policy Does not bar, but reduces recovery in proportion to P’s fault. (1) harshness of all-or-nothing contributory negligence rule; (2) juries were adjusting verdicts anyway; (3) better to monitor w/ judicial oversight. Pure allows recovery in proportion to harm. Modified bars recovery when P is either 50% or 50.1% or more responsible. Depends on Jx. BUT (1) Shd neg Ps be allowed to recover? (2) Comparative neg introduces administrative complexity; (3) prolongs litigation, favors wealthy. Causation Cause in Fact Grimstad (lifevests) No but-for causation in the absence of evidence that omitted precautions would have stopped the harm. Lone Palm Hotel (lifeguard) When P cannot prove causation due to D’s negligence, once P proves negligence burden shifts to D to disprove causation. Zuchowicz (3xRx) Calabresi only When (1) a side effect is the result of a drug; AND (2) drug is negligently prescribed; THEN P has a rebuttable presumption of causation. Union Stock Yards Under CL, only joint not several liability. Ps choose D. (Spurred legislation softening the rule). Joint Liability Any D can be held 100% liable. (Assures Ps will be compensated; even when $D is less neg than P) Several Liability Each D responsible for only their share (either pro rata or proportionate neg – depends upon the statute). Kingston (2 fires) Concurrent When causes are concurrent and each independently would cause the harm, each tortfeasor is jointly liable. (Supported by RTT §27) Summers v. Tice Alternative When (1) P proves each D was negligent; (2) joins all potential Ds; and (3) proves one or the others caused the harm; THEN Ds are alternately liable. I.e. joint liability, but Ds may crossclaim. Enterprise Liability (bottle caps) Industry liable as a whole when: (1) D’s joint control of the risks; (2) least cost avoiders; (3) providing remedy to innocent Ps Lead Industry Ass’n No recovery: (1) No mkt share liability b/c expansive time period (>100yrs); (2) lead paint not a fungible product; (3) no alternative liability b/c not simultaneous act, not all Ds joined; (4) lead does not have a signature harm; P cannot rule out other causes. Sindell (DES#1) Mkt Share Liability Mkt. share liability: (1) All Ds are potential tort-feasors; (2) harmful product was fungible; (3) P unable to ID D, by no fault of P; (4) Substantially all potential Ds named. THEN: Ds liable in proportion to mkt share. Hymowitz (DES#2) Since mkt share liability based upon overall risk produced, no exculpation evidence allowed in indiv. cases. MTBE Commingled product liability: IF P proves harmful product of each D present; THEN P can use mkt share theory to determine liability of each D. P won’t reach 100%. Herskovits (% loss) No lost chance: P recovers only when >50% <50% (PROBLEM: blanket release in some cases) Lost chance: same, but when <50%, P recovers proportionately to % lost Proportionality: P recovers proportionately to percentage loss all the time. Proximate Cause Proximate Cause No prox cause when: (1) supervening cause; (2) unforseeable type of harm; (3) unforeseeable P; (4) too remote in time/place; (5) too much liability. Ryan v. NY Ctr. RR No cause of action when harm is too remote from the negligent act. (Here fire spread 130ft.) Polemis (UK) If D is guilty of a negligent act, he is responsible for all of the direct consequences, foreseeable or not. Emergency rule Intervening human acts that are ordinary and natural results of D’s neg are not supervening causes. Palsgraf P cannot recover unless D’s negligent act is negligent w/r/t P. Foreseeable plaintiff. Wagon Mound #1 (UK-wharf) P cannot recover unless for a reasonably foreseeable type of harm. Foreseeable harm. (Consider that P’s action played a role in the fire). Wagon Mound #2 (UK-ship) P recovers because fire deemed to be a reasonably foreseeable type of harm w/r/t the ship. (Consider P’s action did not play a role in the fire). Smith v. Brain Leech & Co. Thin Skull Plaintiff: P can recover for any direct consequences of D’s negligence. (Characterized as extent, not type of harm. Steinheiser (schizophrenic car accident) P allowed to reach the jury on the question of whether accident was the triggering event of the unforeseeable type of harm. D allowed to argue that illness may have developed in any event as a way of reducing damages. Kinsman Transit (drawbridge-flood) US courts take into account: (1) directness of harm; (2) degree of unforseeability of type vs. extent of harm; (3) whether D’s negligence causes other damage for which it is already liable. Mitchell (miscarriage) OLD RULE: under CL, fright/emotional distress w/o contact CANNOT be causal basis for injury. Dillon (sister) Zone of danger test: may recover for negligent infliction of emotional harm. Factors: (1) physical proximity; (2) direct perception; (3) relationship to victim. P needs to prove pathological diagnosis. Duty Hurley (physician) No liability for refusing to care for the sick. Generally no liability for non-feasance. UNLESS one takes an affirmative step to rescue. Addie & Sons (kids) Buch (immigrant) Under CL, landowners owe no duty of care to trespassers. CL Categories Trespassers – no duty Licensees – duty to warn of concealed danger Guests – duty of reasonable care Rowland (faucet) California only Rejects CL. Factors: (1) foreseeability of harm to P; (2) certainty of injury; (3) connex b/w injury + conduct; (4) moral blame; (5) prevention policy; (6) burden to Ds; (7) insurance scheme; (8) CL categories. Kline (Mass Ave) Landlords have duty to protect tenants against probably & predictable 3rd party attacks in common areas of bldg. IF: (1) notice of repeat criminal acts; (2) occurs on premises under LL control; (3) reasonable to expect re-offense; (4) LL has exclusive pwr to prevent. Consider: (1) causation defense for LL; (2) burden-shifting when assailants unknown; (3) contrib. neg. Tarasoff (insane) One who (1) takes charge of a person, (2) who makes credible threats to a 3rd party, has a duty to warn the 3rd party to prevent future harm. R.2d §319 One who (1) takes charge of person (2) whom he knows or should know is likely to cause bodily harm to others if not controlled, has a duty to control the third person to prevent him from doing such harm. Creates the danger D’s have an affirmative duty to rescue if they create the danger, even if they created the danger non-negligently. Strict Liability Foundations Bushey Employers are vicariously liable for actions of their agents if the action is done in the scope of employment (the action is characteristic of the business activity OR serving the master). R.2d §519 Abnormally dangerous activity is subject to SL, limited to the kind of harm which makes it dangerous. R.2d §520 Abnormally dangerous activity: (1) high degree of risk to person/property; (2) magnitude of potential harm; (3) inability to eliminate risks w/ care; (4) abnormality of the activity; (5) inappropriateness of place; (6) social value small compared with risks. Indiana Harbor Belt RR (RR chemicals) SL not appropriate for D where no: (1) Ability to ? location; (2) ? fundamental nature of activity; (3) abandon activity. (In this case SL would be appropriate to impose on the carrier, but not mfr) R.2d Nuisance Substantial non-trespassory invasion of another’s interest in use & enjoyment of land. Intentional & Unreasonable (3 cases): (1) harm>utility injunction + damages; (2) serious & compensable damages (no injunction); (3) severe & non-compensable damages (possible effect of enjoining activity) Unintentional (one time) & Otherwise Actionable as: (A) Neg; (B) Reckless; (3) Abnormally dangerous. CL Threshold Test When the harm is substantial, courts grant P an injunction. Unless D’s activity is in the public interest. P may sell the injunction back to D. Coase Theorem Assuming zero transaction costs, the socially benefitial activity will prevail regardless of where the law assigns the property right. BUT given transaction costs the placement of the legal rule may lead to inefficient outcomes. Generally, better to disfavor the cheaper cost avoider. Ensign (dogs) It is a consideration, but not a categorical defense that P came to the nuisance. Coming to the Nuisance Economically efficient rule: of two incompatible land uses, the one which had but did not take the opportunity to avoid creating costs of incompatibility should bear the costs. Boomer (cement) Where P seeks to enjoin and (a) P suffers little loss, (b) D suffers great loss, and (c) D’s activity has social & pvt utility, courts may grant an injunction which is vacated upon payment permanent damages to Ps. Spur v. Del Webb (feedlot) (1) Shd D’s activity continue? (2) Who bears the cost that results from allocation of the property right? Whr P gets a windfall by the allocation of a property right, P must compensate D for unjust enrichment. Products Liability Winterbottom (mail) Whr no K privity b/w P&D no duty of care. OLD CL RULE. Liability to 3rd parties only for products that (A) preserve/destroy human life (Winchester); (B) latent defect w/o notice (Kuellig putty concealment) MacPherson v. Buick If the nature of a thing is reasonably certain to be dangerous if used in a foreseeable way, then mfr has a duty of care to 3rd parties. EVOLVING RULE. Escola v. Coca Cola Traynor concurring Mfr is SL when placing product into mkt, knowing it to be used w/o inspection, & P proves causation. Limited to normal proper use. Henningsen v. Bloomfield Motors Essentially SL for manufacturing defects. Non-disclaimable warranty of merchantability. SL runs from mfr to end user. EVOLVING RULE. Defective Warning Cost of warning with Probability of injury and Magnitude of injury Duty of reasonable care (e.g. peanuts), but no duty for obvious dangers (e.g. knives). Unusually unsafe products Use may be permitted if danger is outweighed by not using (e.g. rabies vaccine) R.3d Products §3 Causation due to product defect may be inferred when: (a) incident is of a kind that ordinarily occurs as a result of defect; (b) P rules out causes other than the defect. Speller (fridge) Adopts R.3d §3: P is not required to prove the specific defect. Micallef (printing) P may recover form design defects that are open and obvious so long as the unintended use is reasonably foreseeable. Barker v. Lull 2 Tests for Defects (Cts use both) Consumer Expectations: P shows that product failed to perform as reasonably expected by consumers. Risk-benefit: (1) P shows proximate cause; (2) D shows no alt design is more cost-justified MacDonald (stroke) Learned intermediary doctrine: duty to warn only the doctor, EXCEPT where patient decision-making is more active (e.g. birth control) Hood (blade guard) If a product has been altered in the specific way a warning forbids, the alterations defeat liability. (Design defect may, however, survive some alterations) Liriano (meat gndr) Calabresi only When D’s neg is wrongful b/c it’s likely to cause the type of harm that ensued, evidence of neg is enough to establish a prima facie case of cause-in-fact. Burden shift to D to show no factual cause. Preemption Congress may expressly or implicitly preempt: (1) Field Preemption or (2) Conflict Preemption: (A) Impossibility preemption (B) Obstacle preemption. Geier (admin case) When state tort law conflicts with the aims of the federal regulatory scheme, fed law trumps. Wyeth (IV push) No federal preemption in case of warning labels. FDA reg provides a floor, not a ceiling. Damages Generally, goals to consider regarding damages are: to provide compensation, deterrence, administrability. Punitive Damages Policu Requires more than negligence. (Policy: (1) extra damages offset concealment; (2) deter harmful activity; (3) no worries about over-deterence; (4) otherwise damages may be trivial; (5) substitutes for crim law: (a) crim system may be overburdened, (b) lower burden of proof allows for some level of justice. Compensatory Includes pecuniary/economic losses (e.g. lost wages and cost of care) as well as non-pecuniary damages (e.g. pain and suffering and loss of enjoyment of life). McDougald (coma) Cognitive awareness is necessary when considering loss of enjoyment of life. Loss of enjoyment is not sep category from pain and suffering. Per Diem At trial, lawyers may advise juries determining pain + suffering to put a numerical value on a small unit of time. That time is then multiplied out over Ps lifetime. (favors young victims, raises issues of wage discrimination across race and gender, considerations that P will remain in workforce) Duncan (quad’gic) Ct reduces based on other jury verdicts, considers P’s reduced life-expectancy due to the injury. Damage Caps Some Jxs limit the amounts that P’s can collect. State Farm v. Campbell In determining the Constitutionality of a punitive damage award, consider: (1) the degree of reprehensibility of D’s act; (2) disparity b/w harm or potential harm and the amt of damages. If greater than 9:1, presumptively unconstitutional; (3) the difference between punitive damages and other civil or criminal penalties authorized to punish Ds. Grimshaw (pinto) Company’s own CBA may be used as evidence suggesting a conscious disregard of a design defect. Economic Damages Ps allowed to recover for purely economic damages only in cases of intentional tort or for neg when P proves injury. Cf. evolution of emotional harm. Tort Reform STATUTORY REFORM OF TORT DOCTRINE Tort reform results from crises of increasing frequency of suits and increasing insurance liability costs. Historically, reforms have mostly modified the law governing damages in tort law. Most frequent reforms: absolute dollar ceilings on pain and suffering and punitive damages; limitations or elimination of joint and several liability; abolition of the collateral source rule. Two views on what spurred these legislative reforms The increase in the frequency and costs of suits spurred the need for Ds to predict the scope of liability. More cynical view: potential Ds wanted relief from the increased costs WORKERS COMPENSATION Rise of industrial injuries led to strains on the tort system. Legal doctrines barred Ps’ recovery: assumption of the risk, contributory negligence, fellow servant rule Many workplace injuries were not the result of anyone’s negligence Compensation schemes have 3 components: (A) compensable event; (B) measure of recovery; (C) payment mechanism. Workers compensation modified (A) and (B), yielding systemic benefits in (C) THE COMPENSABLE EVENT Scheme permits compensation for non-negligently caused injury while abolishing tort liability for the employer. Only available defense is that P intended to cause his own injury or acted with wanton disregard. THE MEASURE OF RECOVERY Greater numbers entitled to compensation; resolution via an administrative board reduces administrative costs. The amount of recovery is limited to account for the increased ease of recovery. No recovery at all for pain and suffering; (2) Medical expenses are paid periodically as they are incurred; (3) Statutes set schedule of recovery (e.g. for lost eye, hand, use of legs, etc.), which reduces administrative costs. THE PAYMENT MECHANISM Because the employer remains liable the incentive to deter injuries/accidents remains In a sense the incentive is strengthened b/c an employer is SL for workplace injuries. Some studies show that Workers Comp has resulted in substantial safety incentive effects. Critics argue the benefits levels are too low; periodic payments encourage malingering; with the rise of fungible claims (e.g. stress, back pain) difficulty determining whether injury is work-related. AUTO NO-FAULT First step was to require auto insurance for motorists, covering the cost resulting from accidents irrespective of neg Auto insurance does not squarely fit the workers comp mold b/c both parties in auto context are similarly situated Injurer & victim cannot be identified in advance; (2) Doesn’t necessarily follow that the uninjured party is the injurer Resolution: victim SL for own harms. Auto No-fault: (1) abolition of tort liability; (2) mandatory purchase of insurance. “PURE” NO-FAULT Compensable event is only in auto context; measure of recovery is reduced to a minimum, but drivers may elect to raise the minimum; compensation is paid by “first party” insurance. Critics argue that eliminating tort liability entirely would cause an increasing the accident rate; corrective justice requires the injurer to compensate the victim. Proponents respond that a driver who is not already sufficiently concerned for her own safety would not be deterred by the extra liability; administrative cost savings reduce the need for attorneys, give money to victims. Major resistance by attorneys and no adoption in any state of Pure No-fault. “REAL” NO-FAULT: Abolishes tort liability only for less serious injuries. Claims that surpass a monetary threshold or a verbal threshold (i.e. list of injuries) are allowed. Critics charge that it is no cheaper than the tort system “ADD-ON” NO-FAULT: Tort liability remains untouched; mandatory purchase of no-fault medical and lost-wage insurance. THE FUTURE OF NO-FAULT MEDICAL NO-FAULT: Hard to ID the compensable event b/c people seek medical treatment when already ill or injured. PRODUCT NO-FAULT: Compensable event limited to something like “arising out of the use of defective products.” TARGETED NO-FAULT: E.g. National Childh’d Vaccine Injury Act; 9/11 Victim Compensation Fund; Gulf Coast RECAP – FINAL CLASS NOTES Administrative Costs & Difficulty in Fact-finding in the Current System Greatest costs in the tort system comes from lawyers; more money goes to lawyers than injured Ps Highly technical issues do not lend themselves to tort; but even everyday matters (e.g. car accidents) difficult to prove. Issues of horizontal equity; current system accommodates enormous variation S flow of industrial injury introduced repeat players and repeat harm Workers Comp system. More efficient; gave up on tort as way of ensuring optimal deterrence complete compensation; OSHA came in to provide ex ante deterrence; created risks of logjam and industry capture; risk of ossification of compensation grids. CONTEMPORARY EXAMPLES OF ALTERNATIVES: 9/11 & GULF COAST Set up ex post to handle claims against common D’s, common questions of fault and causation, but different damages. Centralized decision-maker provides: uniform criteria, fewer attorneys, overall less-expensive and time-consuming. Systems did not force Ps into the system; Ps could choose between predictability and a greater payout. Gulf Coast: the private tort system provided better results: more closure for Ds, higher payouts for Ps. MISC Even individualized claims can be aggregated w/in the tort system; easier when there are limited Ds, but possible when there are many Ds, but common questions supervene. Actions can be routinized. The actual system is fairly similar to a more formal system; BUT we have more dynamic system w/ possibility for new systems of liability. Checklist INTENTIONAL TORTS BATTERY TRESPASS (land, chattels) CONVERSION MEDICAL MALPRACTICE INFORMED CONSENT CUSTOM YBARRA – RES IPSA LOQUITUR ZUCHOWICZ – CAUSATION NUISANCE COMMON LAW THRESHOLD TEST RESTATEMENT INTENTIONAL & UNREASONABLE (3 KINDS) UNINTENTIONAL & NEGLIGENT/RECKLESS ABNORMALLY DANGEROUS ACTIVITY STRICT LIABILITY VICARIOUS LIABILITY NEGLIGENT HIRING NUISANCE ULTRA-HAZARDOUS MANUFACTURING DEFECTS DUTY - NEGLIGENCE NEGLIGENCE HAND FORMULA DESIGN DEFECTS AFFIRMATIVE DUTIES DUTY TO WARN SPECIAL RELATIONSHIPS BREACH NEGLIGENCE PER SE CUSTOM RES IPSA LOQUITUR FACTUAL CAUSE JOINT LIABILITY SEVERAL LIABILITY ALTERNATIVE LIABILITY MARKET SHARE LIABILITY COMMINGLED PRODUCT LIABILITY LOST CHANCE LONE PALM PRESUMPTION OF CAUSATION ZUCHOWICZ OR LIRIANO (RES IPSA FOR CAUSATION) PROXIMATE CAUSE POLEMIS TYPE OF HARM EXTENT OF HARM FORESEEABLE PLAINTIFF SUPERVENING CAUSE EMOTIONAL HARM DEFENSES CONTRIBUTORY NEGLIGENCE – PURE COMPARATIVE PRIMARY ASSUMPTION OF THE RISK SECONDARY ASSUMPTION OF THE RISK SEATBELT LAST CLEAR CHANCE CUSTOM SELF-DEFENSE DEFENSE OF PROPERTY DAMAGES PUNITIVE DAMAGES COMPENSATORY DAMAGES PECUNIARY DAMAGES NON-PECUNIARY DAMAGES PURELY ECONOMIC LOSS JUDGE vs. JURY INSUFFICIENT OR DISPOSITIVE JUDGE PERMISSIBLE OR REBUTTABLE JURY

Related Downloads
Explore
Post your homework questions and get free online help from our incredible volunteers
  1191 People Browsing
 129 Signed Up Today
Your Opinion
How often do you eat-out per week?
Votes: 79

Previous poll results: Do you believe in global warming?